7. Using Newton’s Method to Solve Economic Models#
Contents
See also
GPU: A version of this lecture which makes use of jax to run the code
on a GPU
is available here
7.1. Overview#
Many economic problems involve finding fixed points or zeros (sometimes called “roots”) of functions.
For example, in a simple supply and demand model, an equilibrium price is one that makes excess demand zero.
In other words, an equilibrium is a zero of the excess demand function.
There are various computational techniques for solving for fixed points and zeros.
In this lecture we study an important gradient-based technique called Newton’s method.
Newton’s method does not always work but, in situations where it does, convergence is often fast when compared to other methods.
The lecture will apply Newton’s method in one-dimensional and multi-dimensional settings to solve fixed-point and zero-finding problems.
When finding the fixed point of a function \(f\), Newton’s method updates an existing guess of the fixed point by solving for the fixed point of a linear approximation to the function \(f\).
When finding the zero of a function \(f\), Newton’s method updates an existing guess by solving for the zero of a linear approximation to the function \(f\).
To build intuition, we first consider an easy, one-dimensional fixed point problem where we know the solution and solve it using both successive approximation and Newton’s method.
Then we apply Newton’s method to multi-dimensional settings to solve market for equilibria with multiple goods.
At the end of the lecture we leverage the power of automatic
differentiation in autograd
to solve a very high-dimensional equilibrium problem
!pip install autograd
Show code cell output
Collecting autograd
Downloading autograd-1.7.0-py3-none-any.whl.metadata (7.5 kB)
Requirement already satisfied: numpy in /opt/conda/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from autograd) (1.26.4)
Downloading autograd-1.7.0-py3-none-any.whl (52 kB)
Installing collected packages: autograd
Successfully installed autograd-1.7.0
WARNING: Running pip as the 'root' user can result in broken permissions and conflicting behaviour with the system package manager, possibly rendering your system unusable.It is recommended to use a virtual environment instead: https://pip.pypa.io/warnings/venv. Use the --root-user-action option if you know what you are doing and want to suppress this warning.
We use the following imports in this lecture
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt
from collections import namedtuple
from scipy.optimize import root
from autograd import jacobian
# Thinly-wrapped numpy to enable automatic differentiation
import autograd.numpy as np
plt.rcParams["figure.figsize"] = (10, 5.7)
7.2. Fixed Point Computation Using Newton’s Method#
In this section we solve the fixed point of the law of motion for capital in the setting of the Solow growth model.
We will inspect the fixed point visually, solve it by successive approximation, and then apply Newton’s method to achieve faster convergence.
7.2.1. The Solow Model#
In the Solow growth model, assuming Cobb-Douglas production technology and zero population growth, the law of motion for capital is
Here
\(k_t\) is capital stock per worker,
\(A, \alpha>0\) are production parameters, \(\alpha<1\)
\(s>0\) is a savings rate, and
\(\delta \in(0,1)\) is a rate of depreciation
In this example, we wish to calculate the unique strictly positive fixed point of \(g\), the law of motion for capital.
In other words, we seek a \(k^* > 0\) such that \(g(k^*)=k^*\).
such a \(k^*\) is called a steady state, since \(k_t = k^*\) implies \(k_{t+1} = k^*\).
Using pencil and paper to solve \(g(k)=k\), you will be able to confirm that
7.2.2. Implementation#
Let’s store our parameters in namedtuple
to help us keep our code clean and concise.
SolowParameters = namedtuple("SolowParameters", ('A', 's', 'α', 'δ'))
This function creates a suitable namedtuple
with default parameter values.
def create_solow_params(A=2.0, s=0.3, α=0.3, δ=0.4):
"Creates a Solow model parameterization with default values."
return SolowParameters(A=A, s=s, α=α, δ=δ)
The next two functions implement the law of motion (7.1) and store the true fixed point \(k^*\).
def g(k, params):
A, s, α, δ = params
return A * s * k**α + (1 - δ) * k
def exact_fixed_point(params):
A, s, α, δ = params
return ((s * A) / δ)**(1/(1 - α))
Here is a function to provide a 45 degree plot of the dynamics.
def plot_45(params, ax, fontsize=14):
k_min, k_max = 0.0, 3.0
k_grid = np.linspace(k_min, k_max, 1200)
# Plot the functions
lb = r"$g(k) = sAk^{\alpha} + (1 - \delta)k$"
ax.plot(k_grid, g(k_grid, params), lw=2, alpha=0.6, label=lb)
ax.plot(k_grid, k_grid, "k--", lw=1, alpha=0.7, label="45")
# Show and annotate the fixed point
kstar = exact_fixed_point(params)
fps = (kstar,)
ax.plot(fps, fps, "go", ms=10, alpha=0.6)
ax.annotate(r"$k^* = (sA / \delta)^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha}}$",
xy=(kstar, kstar),
xycoords="data",
xytext=(20, -20),
textcoords="offset points",
fontsize=fontsize)
ax.legend(loc="upper left", frameon=False, fontsize=fontsize)
ax.set_yticks((0, 1, 2, 3))
ax.set_yticklabels((0.0, 1.0, 2.0, 3.0), fontsize=fontsize)
ax.set_ylim(0, 3)
ax.set_xlabel("$k_t$", fontsize=fontsize)
ax.set_ylabel("$k_{t+1}$", fontsize=fontsize)
Let’s look at the 45 degree diagram for two parameterizations.
params = create_solow_params()
fig, ax = plt.subplots(figsize=(8, 8))
plot_45(params, ax)
plt.show()
params = create_solow_params(α=0.05, δ=0.5)
fig, ax = plt.subplots(figsize=(8, 8))
plot_45(params, ax)
plt.show()
We see that \(k^*\) is indeed the unique positive fixed point.
7.2.2.1. Successive Approximation#
First let’s compute the fixed point using successive approximation.
In this case, successive approximation means repeatedly updating capital from some initial state \(k_0\) using the law of motion.
Here’s a time series from a particular choice of \(k_0\).
def compute_iterates(k_0, f, params, n=25):
"Compute time series of length n generated by arbitrary function f."
k = k_0
k_iterates = []
for t in range(n):
k_iterates.append(k)
k = f(k, params)
return k_iterates
params = create_solow_params()
k_0 = 0.25
k_series = compute_iterates(k_0, g, params)
k_star = exact_fixed_point(params)
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
ax.plot(k_series, 'o')
ax.plot([k_star] * len(k_series), 'k--')
ax.set_ylim(0, 3)
plt.show()
Let’s see the output for a long time series.
k_series = compute_iterates(k_0, g, params, n=10_000)
k_star_approx = k_series[-1]
k_star_approx
1.7846741842265788
This is close to the true value.
k_star
1.7846741842265788
7.2.2.2. Newton’s Method#
In general, when applying Newton’s fixed point method to some function \(g\), we start with a guess \(x_0\) of the fixed point and then update by solving for the fixed point of a tangent line at \(x_0\).
To begin with, we recall that the first-order approximation of \(g\) at \(x_0\) (i.e., the first order Taylor approximation of \(g\) at \(x_0\)) is the function
We solve for the fixed point of \(\hat g\) by calculating the \(x_1\) that solves
Generalising the process above, Newton’s fixed point method iterates on
To implement Newton’s method we observe that the derivative of the law of motion for capital (7.1) is
Let’s define this:
def Dg(k, params):
A, s, α, δ = params
return α * A * s * k**(α-1) + (1 - δ)
Here’s a function \(q\) representing (7.3).
def q(k, params):
return (g(k, params) - Dg(k, params) * k) / (1 - Dg(k, params))
Now let’s plot some trajectories.
def plot_trajectories(params,
k0_a=0.8, # first initial condition
k0_b=3.1, # second initial condition
n=20, # length of time series
fs=14): # fontsize
fig, axes = plt.subplots(2, 1, figsize=(10, 6))
ax1, ax2 = axes
ks1 = compute_iterates(k0_a, g, params, n)
ax1.plot(ks1, "-o", label="successive approximation")
ks2 = compute_iterates(k0_b, g, params, n)
ax2.plot(ks2, "-o", label="successive approximation")
ks3 = compute_iterates(k0_a, q, params, n)
ax1.plot(ks3, "-o", label="newton steps")
ks4 = compute_iterates(k0_b, q, params, n)
ax2.plot(ks4, "-o", label="newton steps")
for ax in axes:
ax.plot(k_star * np.ones(n), "k--")
ax.legend(fontsize=fs, frameon=False)
ax.set_ylim(0.6, 3.2)
ax.set_yticks((k_star,))
ax.set_yticklabels(("$k^*$",), fontsize=fs)
ax.set_xticks(np.linspace(0, 19, 20))
plt.show()
params = create_solow_params()
plot_trajectories(params)
We can see that Newton’s method converges faster than successive approximation.
7.3. Root-Finding in One Dimension#
In the previous section we computed fixed points.
In fact Newton’s method is more commonly associated with the problem of finding zeros of functions.
Let’s discuss this “root-finding” problem and then show how it is connected to the problem of finding fixed points.
7.3.1. Newton’s Method for Zeros#
Let’s suppose we want to find an \(x\) such that \(f(x)=0\) for some smooth function \(f\) mapping real numbers to real numbers.
Suppose we have a guess \(x_0\) and we want to update it to a new point \(x_1\).
As a first step, we take the first-order approximation of \(f\) around \(x_0\):
Now we solve for the zero of \(\hat f\).
In particular, we set \(\hat{f}(x_1) = 0\) and solve for \(x_1\) to get
Generalizing the formula above, for one-dimensional zero-finding problems, Newton’s method iterates on
The following code implements the iteration (7.5)
def newton(f, Df, x_0, tol=1e-7, max_iter=100_000):
x = x_0
# Implement the zero-finding formula
def q(x):
return x - f(x) / Df(x)
error = tol + 1
n = 0
while error > tol:
n += 1
if(n > max_iter):
raise Exception('Max iteration reached without convergence')
y = q(x)
error = np.abs(x - y)
x = y
print(f'iteration {n}, error = {error:.5f}')
return x
Numerous libraries implement Newton’s method in one dimension, including SciPy, so the code is just for illustrative purposes.
(That said, when we want to apply Newton’s method using techniques such as automatic differentiation or GPU acceleration, it will be helpful to know how to implement Newton’s method ourselves.)
7.3.2. Application to Finding Fixed Points#
Now consider again the Solow fixed-point calculation, where we solve for \(k\) satisfying \(g(k) = k\).
We can convert to this to a zero-finding problem by setting \(f(x) := g(x)-x\).
Any zero of \(f\) is clearly a fixed point of \(g\).
Let’s apply this idea to the Solow problem
params = create_solow_params()
k_star_approx_newton = newton(f=lambda x: g(x, params) - x,
Df=lambda x: Dg(x, params) - 1,
x_0=0.8)
iteration 1, error = 1.27209
iteration 2, error = 0.28180
iteration 3, error = 0.00561
iteration 4, error = 0.00000
iteration 5, error = 0.00000
k_star_approx_newton
1.7846741842265788
The result confirms the descent we saw in the graphs above: a very accurate result is reached with only 5 iterations.
7.4. Multivariate Newton’s Method#
In this section, we introduce a two-good problem, present a
visualization of the problem, and solve for the equilibrium of the two-good market
using both a zero finder in SciPy
and Newton’s method.
We then expand the idea to a larger market with 5,000 goods and compare the performance of the two methods again.
We will see a significant performance gain when using Netwon’s method.
7.4.1. A Two Goods Market Equilibrium#
Let’s start by computing the market equilibrium of a two-good problem.
We consider a market for two related products, good 0 and good 1, with price vector \(p = (p_0, p_1)\)
Supply of good \(i\) at price \(p\),
Demand of good \(i\) at price \(p\) is,
Here \(c_i\), \(b_i\) and \(a_{ij}\) are parameters.
For example, the two goods might be computer components that are typically used together, in which case they are complements. Hence demand depends on the price of both components.
The excess demand function is,
An equilibrium price vector \(p^*\) satisfies \(e_i(p^*) = 0\).
We set
for this particular question.
7.4.1.1. A Graphical Exploration#
Since our problem is only two-dimensional, we can use graphical analysis to visualize and help understand the problem.
Our first step is to define the excess demand function
The function below calculates the excess demand for given parameters
def e(p, A, b, c):
return np.exp(- A @ p) + c - b * np.sqrt(p)
Our default parameter values will be
A = np.array([
[0.5, 0.4],
[0.8, 0.2]
])
b = np.ones(2)
c = np.ones(2)
At a price level of \(p = (1, 0.5)\), the excess demand is
ex_demand = e((1.0, 0.5), A, b, c)
print(f'The excess demand for good 0 is {ex_demand[0]:.3f} \n'
f'The excess demand for good 1 is {ex_demand[1]:.3f}')
The excess demand for good 0 is 0.497
The excess demand for good 1 is 0.699
Next we plot the two functions \(e_0\) and \(e_1\) on a grid of \((p_0, p_1)\) values, using contour surfaces and lines.
We will use the following function to build the contour plots
def plot_excess_demand(ax, good=0, grid_size=100, grid_max=4, surface=True):
# Create a 100x100 grid
p_grid = np.linspace(0, grid_max, grid_size)
z = np.empty((100, 100))
for i, p_1 in enumerate(p_grid):
for j, p_2 in enumerate(p_grid):
z[i, j] = e((p_1, p_2), A, b, c)[good]
if surface:
cs1 = ax.contourf(p_grid, p_grid, z.T, alpha=0.5)
plt.colorbar(cs1, ax=ax, format="%.6f")
ctr1 = ax.contour(p_grid, p_grid, z.T, levels=[0.0])
ax.set_xlabel("$p_0$")
ax.set_ylabel("$p_1$")
ax.set_title(f'Excess Demand for Good {good}')
plt.clabel(ctr1, inline=1, fontsize=13)
Here’s our plot of \(e_0\):
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
plot_excess_demand(ax, good=0)
plt.show()
Here’s our plot of \(e_1\):
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
plot_excess_demand(ax, good=1)
plt.show()
We see the black contour line of zero, which tells us when \(e_i(p)=0\).
For a price vector \(p\) such that \(e_i(p)=0\) we know that good \(i\) is in equilibrium (demand equals supply).
If these two contour lines cross at some price vector \(p^*\), then \(p^*\) is an equilibrium price vector.
fig, ax = plt.subplots(figsize=(10, 5.7))
for good in (0, 1):
plot_excess_demand(ax, good=good, surface=False)
plt.show()
It seems there is an equilibrium close to \(p = (1.6, 1.5)\).
7.4.1.2. Using a Multidimensional Root Finder#
To solve for \(p^*\) more precisely, we use a zero-finding algorithm from scipy.optimize
.
We supply \(p = (1, 1)\) as our initial guess.
init_p = np.ones(2)
This uses the modified Powell method to find the zero
%%time
solution = root(lambda p: e(p, A, b, c), init_p, method='hybr')
CPU times: user 189 μs, sys: 15 μs, total: 204 μs
Wall time: 205 μs
Here’s the resulting value:
p = solution.x
p
array([1.57080182, 1.46928838])
This looks close to our guess from observing the figure. We can plug it back into \(e\) to test that \(e(p) \approx 0\):
np.max(np.abs(e(p, A, b, c)))
2.0383694732117874e-13
This is indeed a very small error.
7.4.1.3. Adding Gradient Information#
In many cases, for zero-finding algorithms applied to smooth functions, supplying the Jacobian of the function leads to better convergence properties.
Here we manually calculate the elements of the Jacobian
def jacobian_e(p, A, b, c):
p_0, p_1 = p
a_00, a_01 = A[0, :]
a_10, a_11 = A[1, :]
j_00 = -a_00 * np.exp(-a_00 * p_0) - (b[0]/2) * p_0**(-1/2)
j_01 = -a_01 * np.exp(-a_01 * p_1)
j_10 = -a_10 * np.exp(-a_10 * p_0)
j_11 = -a_11 * np.exp(-a_11 * p_1) - (b[1]/2) * p_1**(-1/2)
J = [[j_00, j_01],
[j_10, j_11]]
return np.array(J)
%%time
solution = root(lambda p: e(p, A, b, c),
init_p,
jac=lambda p: jacobian_e(p, A, b, c),
method='hybr')
CPU times: user 251 μs, sys: 21 μs, total: 272 μs
Wall time: 264 μs
Now the solution is even more accurate (although, in this low-dimensional problem, the difference is quite small):
p = solution.x
np.max(np.abs(e(p, A, b, c)))
1.3322676295501878e-15
7.4.1.4. Using Newton’s Method#
Now let’s use Newton’s method to compute the equilibrium price using the multivariate version of Newton’s method
This is a multivariate version of (7.5)
(Here \(J_e(p_n)\) is the Jacobian of \(e\) evaluated at \(p_n\).)
The iteration starts from some initial guess of the price vector \(p_0\).
Here, instead of coding Jacobian by hand, We use the jacobian()
function in the autograd
library to auto-differentiate and calculate the Jacobian.
With only slight modification, we can generalize our previous attempt to multi-dimensional problems
def newton(f, x_0, tol=1e-5, max_iter=10):
x = x_0
q = lambda x: x - np.linalg.solve(jacobian(f)(x), f(x))
error = tol + 1
n = 0
while error > tol:
n+=1
if(n > max_iter):
raise Exception('Max iteration reached without convergence')
y = q(x)
if(any(np.isnan(y))):
raise Exception('Solution not found with NaN generated')
error = np.linalg.norm(x - y)
x = y
print(f'iteration {n}, error = {error:.5f}')
print('\n' + f'Result = {x} \n')
return x
def e(p, A, b, c):
return np.exp(- np.dot(A, p)) + c - b * np.sqrt(p)
We find the algorithm terminates in 4 steps
%%time
p = newton(lambda p: e(p, A, b, c), init_p)
iteration 1, error = 0.62515
iteration 2, error = 0.11152
iteration 3, error = 0.00258
iteration 4, error = 0.00000
Result = [1.57080182 1.46928838]
CPU times: user 2.07 ms, sys: 173 μs, total: 2.24 ms
Wall time: 2 ms
np.max(np.abs(e(p, A, b, c)))
1.461053500406706e-13
The result is very accurate.
With the larger overhead, the speed is not better than the optimized scipy
function.
7.4.2. A High-Dimensional Problem#
Our next step is to investigate a large market with 3,000 goods.
A JAX version of this section using GPU accelerated linear algebra and automatic differentiation is available here
The excess demand function is essentially the same, but now the matrix \(A\) is \(3000 \times 3000\) and the parameter vectors \(b\) and \(c\) are \(3000 \times 1\).
dim = 3000
np.random.seed(123)
# Create a random matrix A and normalize the rows to sum to one
A = np.random.rand(dim, dim)
A = np.asarray(A)
s = np.sum(A, axis=0)
A = A / s
# Set up b and c
b = np.ones(dim)
c = np.ones(dim)
Here’s our initial condition
init_p = np.ones(dim)
%%time
p = newton(lambda p: e(p, A, b, c), init_p)
iteration 1, error = 23.22267
iteration 2, error = 3.94538
iteration 3, error = 0.08500
iteration 4, error = 0.00004
iteration 5, error = 0.00000
Result = [1.50185286 1.49865815 1.50028285 ... 1.50875149 1.48724784 1.48577532]
CPU times: user 47.1 s, sys: 195 ms, total: 47.3 s
Wall time: 43.2 s
np.max(np.abs(e(p, A, b, c)))
1.5543122344752192e-15
With the same tolerance, we compare the runtime and accuracy of Newton’s method to SciPy’s root
function
%%time
solution = root(lambda p: e(p, A, b, c),
init_p,
jac=lambda p: jacobian(e)(p, A, b, c),
method='hybr',
tol=1e-5)
CPU times: user 41.4 s, sys: 36.2 ms, total: 41.4 s
Wall time: 40.8 s
p = solution.x
np.max(np.abs(e(p, A, b, c)))
8.295585953721485e-07
7.5. Exercises#
Consider a three-dimensional extension of the Solow fixed point problem with
As before the law of motion is
However \(k_t\) is now a \(3 \times 1\) vector.
Solve for the fixed point using Newton’s method with the following initial values:
Hint
The computation of the fixed point is equivalent to computing \(k^*\) such that \(f(k^*) - k^* = 0\).
If you are unsure about your solution, you can start with the solved example:
with \(s = 0.3\), \(α = 0.3\), and \(δ = 0.4\) and starting value:
The result should converge to the analytical solution.
Solution to Exercise 7.1
Let’s first define the parameters for this problem
A = np.array([[2.0, 3.0, 3.0],
[2.0, 4.0, 2.0],
[1.0, 5.0, 1.0]])
s = 0.2
α = 0.5
δ = 0.8
initLs = [np.ones(3),
np.array([3.0, 5.0, 5.0]),
np.repeat(50.0, 3)]
Then define the multivariate version of the formula for the (7.1)
def multivariate_solow(k, A=A, s=s, α=α, δ=δ):
return (s * np.dot(A, k**α) + (1 - δ) * k)
Let’s run through each starting value and see the output
attempt = 1
for init in initLs:
print(f'Attempt {attempt}: Starting value is {init} \n')
%time k = newton(lambda k: multivariate_solow(k) - k, \
init)
print('-'*64)
attempt += 1
Attempt 1: Starting value is [1. 1. 1.]
iteration 1, error = 50.49630
iteration 2, error = 41.10937
iteration 3, error = 4.29413
iteration 4, error = 0.38543
iteration 5, error = 0.00544
iteration 6, error = 0.00000
Result = [3.84058108 3.87071771 3.41091933]
CPU times: user 3.11 ms, sys: 0 ns, total: 3.11 ms
Wall time: 3.04 ms
----------------------------------------------------------------
Attempt 2: Starting value is [3. 5. 5.]
iteration 1, error = 2.07011
iteration 2, error = 0.12642
iteration 3, error = 0.00060
iteration 4, error = 0.00000
Result = [3.84058108 3.87071771 3.41091933]
CPU times: user 1.77 ms, sys: 0 ns, total: 1.77 ms
Wall time: 1.78 ms
----------------------------------------------------------------
Attempt 3: Starting value is [50. 50. 50.]
iteration 1, error = 73.00943
iteration 2, error = 6.49379
iteration 3, error = 0.68070
iteration 4, error = 0.01620
iteration 5, error = 0.00001
iteration 6, error = 0.00000
Result = [3.84058108 3.87071771 3.41091933]
CPU times: user 2.53 ms, sys: 0 ns, total: 2.53 ms
Wall time: 2.53 ms
----------------------------------------------------------------
We find that the results are invariant to the starting values given the well-defined property of this question.
But the number of iterations it takes to converge is dependent on the starting values.
Let substitute the output back to the formulate to check our last result
multivariate_solow(k) - k
array([-4.4408921e-16, -4.4408921e-16, 4.4408921e-16])
Note the error is very small.
We can also test our results on the known solution
A = np.array([[2.0, 0.0, 0.0],
[0.0, 2.0, 0.0],
[0.0, 0.0, 2.0]])
s = 0.3
α = 0.3
δ = 0.4
init = np.repeat(1.0, 3)
%time k = newton(lambda k: multivariate_solow(k, A=A, s=s, α=α, δ=δ) - k, \
init)
iteration 1, error = 1.57459
iteration 2, error = 0.21345
iteration 3, error = 0.00205
iteration 4, error = 0.00000
Result = [1.78467418 1.78467418 1.78467418]
CPU times: user 2.18 ms, sys: 0 ns, total: 2.18 ms
Wall time: 2.03 ms
The result is very close to the ground truth but still slightly different.
%time k = newton(lambda k: multivariate_solow(k, A=A, s=s, α=α, δ=δ) - k, \
init,\
tol=1e-7)
iteration 1, error = 1.57459
iteration 2, error = 0.21345
iteration 3, error = 0.00205
iteration 4, error = 0.00000
iteration 5, error = 0.00000
Result = [1.78467418 1.78467418 1.78467418]
CPU times: user 2.64 ms, sys: 0 ns, total: 2.64 ms
Wall time: 2.46 ms
We can see it steps towards a more accurate solution.
In this exercise, let’s try different initial values and check how Newton’s method responds to different starting points.
Let’s define a three-good problem with the following default values:
For this exercise, use the following extreme price vectors as initial values:
Set the tolerance to \(0.0\) for more accurate output.
Solution to Exercise 7.2
Define parameters and initial values
A = np.array([
[0.2, 0.1, 0.7],
[0.3, 0.2, 0.5],
[0.1, 0.8, 0.1]
])
b = np.array([1.0, 1.0, 1.0])
c = np.array([1.0, 1.0, 1.0])
initLs = [np.repeat(5.0, 3),
np.ones(3),
np.array([4.5, 0.1, 4.0])]
Let’s run through each initial guess and check the output
attempt = 1
for init in initLs:
print(f'Attempt {attempt}: Starting value is {init} \n')
%time p = newton(lambda p: e(p, A, b, c), \
init, \
tol=1e-15, \
max_iter=15)
print('-'*64)
attempt += 1
Attempt 1: Starting value is [5. 5. 5.]
iteration 1, error = 9.24381
/opt/conda/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages/autograd/tracer.py:48: RuntimeWarning: invalid value encountered in sqrt
return f_raw(*args, **kwargs)
/opt/conda/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages/autograd/numpy/numpy_vjps.py:98: RuntimeWarning: invalid value encountered in power
defvjp(anp.sqrt, lambda ans, x : lambda g: g * 0.5 * x**-0.5)
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Exception Traceback (most recent call last)
File <timed exec>:1
Cell In[34], line 12, in newton(f, x_0, tol, max_iter)
10 y = q(x)
11 if(any(np.isnan(y))):
---> 12 raise Exception('Solution not found with NaN generated')
13 error = np.linalg.norm(x - y)
14 x = y
Exception: Solution not found with NaN generated
----------------------------------------------------------------
Attempt 2: Starting value is [1. 1. 1.]
iteration 1, error = 0.73419
iteration 2, error = 0.12472
iteration 3, error = 0.00269
iteration 4, error = 0.00000
iteration 5, error = 0.00000
iteration 6, error = 0.00000
Result = [1.49744442 1.49744442 1.49744442]
CPU times: user 3.08 ms, sys: 0 ns, total: 3.08 ms
Wall time: 2.79 ms
----------------------------------------------------------------
Attempt 3: Starting value is [4.5 0.1 4. ]
iteration 1, error = 4.89202
iteration 2, error = 1.21206
iteration 3, error = 0.69421
iteration 4, error = 0.16895
iteration 5, error = 0.00521
iteration 6, error = 0.00000
iteration 7, error = 0.00000
iteration 8, error = 0.00000
Result = [1.49744442 1.49744442 1.49744442]
CPU times: user 3.63 ms, sys: 0 ns, total: 3.63 ms
Wall time: 3.33 ms
----------------------------------------------------------------
We can find that Newton’s method may fail for some starting values.
Sometimes it may take a few initial guesses to achieve convergence.
Substitute the result back to the formula to check our result
e(p, A, b, c)
array([ 0.00000000e+00, 0.00000000e+00, -2.22044605e-16])
We can see the result is very accurate.